User Tools

Site Tools


baseline_generation

This is an old revision of the document!


Baseline Generation

On forecasts in simulation models

The purpose of a baseline is to serve as a comparison point or comparison time series for counterfactual analysis. The baseline is interpreted as a projection in time covering the most probable future development of the European agricultural sector under the status-quo policy and including all future changes already foreseen in the current legislation.

Conceptually, the baseline should capture the complex interrelations between technological, structural and preference changes for agricultural products world-wide in combination with changes in policies, population and non-agricultural markets. Given the complexity of these highly interrelated developments, baselines are in most cases not a straight outcome from a model but developed using a combination of trend analysis, model runs and expert consultations. In this process, model parameters such as elasticities and exogenous assumptions, e.g., technological progress captured in yield growth, are adjusted in order to achieve plausible results (as regarded by experts, e.g. European Commission projections). It is almost unavoidable that the process is somewhat intransparent.

The kind of baseline process described above is not specific to CAPRI, but is found also in other large scale modelling projects. Two typical examples are discussed here.

  • In the case of the Aglink modelling system of the OECD, questionnaires are sent out to the OECD Member States covering all endogenous and exogenous variables of Aglink. The Member States fill in time series regarding the future developments for their respective countries. The projections reported by the member states may themselves stem from country specific model baselines, expert consultations, trend analyses or other sources – in many cases, their provenience is not known in detail. The OECD then sets the constant terms in all behavioural equations of Aglink so that the country modules would exactly recover the values for the endogenous variables for that country found in the questionnaires at the values assigned to the exogenous variables. Clearly, as the countries fill their questionnaires without knowing about the future expectations of other OECD Members, the expectations of the different teams e.g. regarding imports/exports or world market prices may differ and lead to values at country level which are mutually not compatible when linked globally together in the modelling framework. To eliminate such differences, the OECD will repeatedly start Aglink to generate technically compatible results and receive comments on these runs which will lead to updated data in the questionnaires and thus new shift terms in the behavioural equations.
  • The second example is that of FAPRI model, where a so-called melting down meeting is organised where the modellers responsible for specific parts of the system come together with market experts. Results are discussed, parameters and assumptions changed until there is consensus. Little is known about how the process works exactly, but both examples underline the interaction between model mechanisms and ex-ante expectations of market experts.

As is the case in other agencies, the CAPRI baseline is also fed by external (“expert”) forecasts, as well as by trend forecasts using data from the national ‘COCO’ and regionalized CAPREG databases (Chapters The Complete and Consistent Data Base (COCO) for the national scale and The Regionalised Data Base (CAPREG)). The purpose of these trend estimates is, on the one hand, to compare expert forecasts with a purely technical extrapolation of time series and, on the other hand, to provide a ‘safety net’ position in case no values from external projection are available. Usually the projections for a CAPRI baseline are a combination of expert data (e.g. from FAO, European Commission, World Bank, other research teams and even private entreprises) and simple statistical trends of data contained in the CAPRI database.

Overview of CAPRI baseline processes

The creation of a baseline in CAPRI is considered a “workstep” in the GUI, and it consists of three distinct tasks. In addition to those three tasks, the modeller will usually want to perform a simulation of “no change” to reproduce the calibrated baseline with the model. Figure below illustrates the principal data flows involved in the baseline process. Each step is further described in a separate section of this chapter.

Figure 10: Overview of CAPRI baseline process


Source: own illustration

The forecast tool CAPTRD uses the consolidated national and regional time series from COCO and CAPREG together with external projections from the AgLink model. The result is a projection for the key variables in the agricultural sector (activity levels and market balances) of all regions in the supply models (EU+) that is consistent with the supply model equations.

  1. Next task is the market model calibration. That task uses the same AgLink projections, complemented with the harmonized trade database GLOBAL (see section The global database components), the baseline policy files, the regional data for the base year (CAPREG) and the regional trends coming from CAPTRD. The output includes a market data set that is consistent with the regional trends, with calibrated parameters to steer behavioural functions, and adds producer prices to be used by the supply models.
  2. The third task is the calibration of the supply models. This step also uses the regional data base, regional trends, and policy files, and calibrates various technical and behavioural economic parameters of the supply models so that the projected regional production is the optimal production at the producer prices coming from the market model calibration.
  3. Finally, the modeller typically wants to perform a simulation using all the calibrated parameters and projected data. The purpose is twofold: to verify that the calibration of the baseline worked as intended and to generate all reports for inspection in the GUI.

Forecast tool CAPTRD

The tool providing projections for the European regions (the EU as of 2019, Turkey, Norway, Albania, Northern Macedonia, Montenegro, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Kosovo and Serbia) in CAPRI is called CAPTRD. It operates in several steps:

  • Step 1 involves independent trends on all series, providing initial forecasts and statistics on the goodness of fit or indirectly on the variability of the series.
  • Step 2 imposes constraints like identities (e.g. production = area * yield) or technical bounds (like non-negativity or maximum yields) and introduces specific expert information given on the MS level.
  • Step 3 includes expert information on aggregate EU markets, typically coming from the AgLink model or GLOBIOM. This external data is not available for all individual countries in CAPRI, but for larger regions. Therefore, several countries must be simultaneously estimated in order to ensure proper use of this important prior information.
  • Step 4 Depending on the aggregation level chosen the MS result may be disaggregated in subsequent steps to the regional level (NUTS2) or even to the level of farm types.

The trends estimated in CAPTRD are subject to consistency restrictions in steps 2 and 3. Hence they are not independent forecasts for each time series and the resulting estimator is hence a system estimator under constraints (e.g. closed area and market balances). Nonetheless, the trends are mechanical in the sense that they respect technological relationships but do not include any information about behavioural functions or policy developments1).

CAPTRD results are in turn only the first of several steps before a full CAPRI baseline is ready to use. The rest of this chapter focuses on CAPTRD.

Step 1: Independent, weighted nonlinear least squares

Before entering into the details it should be stated that ultimately almost any projection may be reduced to a particular type of trend projections, at least if the exogenous inputs, such as population, prices or household expenditure are also projected (usually by other research teams) as functions of time. In this sense trend projection may provide a firm ground on which to build projections and this is exactly their purpose in our work.

The first ingredient in the estimator is the trend curve itself which is defined as:

\begin{equation} X_{r,i,t}^{j,Trend}=a_{r,i,j}+b_{r,i,j}t^{c_{r,i,j}} \end{equation}

where the parameters a, b and c are to be estimated so that the squared deviation between given and estimated data are minimized. The X stands for the data and represents a five dimensional array, spanning up products i and items j (as feed use or production), regions r, points in time t and different data status such as ‘Trend’ or ‘Observed’. The trend curve itself is a kind of Box-Cox transformation, as parameter c is used as the exponent of the trend. For c equal unity, the resulting curve is a straight line, for c between 0 and 1, the curve is concave from below, i.e. increasing but with decreasing rates, whereas for c > 1, the curve is convex from below, i.e. increasing with increasing rates. In order to prevent differences between time points to increase sharply over the projection period, the parameters c are restricted to be below 1.2.

This form has the advantage of ensuring monotonic developments whereas quadratic trends often gave increasing yields for the first part of the projection period and afterwards a decrease. Another conclusion from the early explorations was that it is useful to define the trend variable \(t_{1984} = 0.1, t_{1985} = 0.2, t_{1986} = 0.3 \) etc., giving a potentially strong nonlinearity in the early years of the database (where the frequency of high changes, possibly due to data weaknesses was high) and a rather low nonlinearity in the projection period.

The ex-post period usually covers the period from 1985 towards the end of the underlying CAPREG output (file res_time_series.gdx) which is typically 4-6 years before the current year. The national level COCO data may have somewhat longer series than the regional CAPREG data. To account for this different availability of ex post data the following sets should be distinguished:

  • Expost: defined from the length of the series in CAPREG output res_time_series.gdx
  • Exante: covering any sequence of intermediate result years up to the user specified final year2).
  • ExanteD: Ex ante years with additional COCO1 data (assigned in ‘captrd\ load_coco1_data.gms’)
  • ExpostT: Union of Expost and ExanteD = years with data for trend estimation

The estimator minimises the weighted sum of squares of errors using the trend variable as weights:

\begin{equation} wSSE_{r,i,j}=\sum_{expost} \left(X_{r,i,expost}^{j,"Data"}-a_{r,i,j}+b_{r,i,j}t_{expost}^{c_{r,i,j}}\right)^2t_{expost} \end{equation}

The weighting with the trend was introduced in the exploration phase based on the following considerations and experience. First of all, it reflects the fact that statistics from the early years (mid eighties) are often less reliable then those from later years. Secondly, even if they are reliable, older data will tend to contribute less useful information than more recent ones due to ongoing structural change. For this reason we have discarded any years before 1992 for the New MS, for example, but the data from the mid 90ies may nonetheless represent a situation of transition that should count less than the recent past. In technical terms the step 1 estimates are found by a grid search over selected values of parameter c with analytical OLS estimates for parameters a and b (see ‘captrd\estimate_trends.gms’) that have been found identical to those of the econometric package Eviews for a given value of c (holds also for wSSE).

Step 2.1: Consistency constraints in the trend projection tool

Step 2 adds the consistency conditions and thus transforms the naïve independent trends into a system estimator. In almost all cases, the unrestricted trend estimates from the first step would violate one or several of the consistency conditions. We want to find estimates that both fit into the consistency constraints and exploit the information comprised in the ex-post development in a technical feasible way. Consider the identity that defines production as hectares/herd sizes times yield. Running independent trend estimates for barley area, barley yield and barley production will almost certainly produce estimates where production is not equal to yield times area. One solution would be to drop one of the three estimates, say yield, and replace it instead by the division of forecasted production by forecasted area. However, by doing so, we throw away the information incorporated in the development of barley yield over time. Adding relations between time series hence helps us to exploit more information than is contained in single series.

When consolidating simultaneously the different Step1 estimates, we will minimise the squared deviations from values computed in Step 1, in the following called “supports”, while complying with all constraints. A risk is that shaky trends may give a forecast line with an end point far away from ex-post observations. Hence we need safeguards pulling our estimates to a ‘reasonable’ value in such cases.

The confidence interval from the Step 1 trend estimation will not help, as it will be centred around the last projection value and as it will simply be quite large in case of a bad R². However, we may use the idea underlying the usual test statistics for the parameters related to the trend (a,b,c). These statistics test the probability of (a,b,c) being significantly different from zero. It can be shown that these tests are directly related to R² of the regression. If the zero hypotheses would be true, i.e. if the estimated parameters would have a high probability of being zero, we would not use the trend line, but the mean of the series instead.

This reasoning is the basis for the supports derived from the Step 1 estimates in CAPTRD (‘captrd\define_stats_and_supports.gms’), after some modifications. First of all, we used a three-year average based on the last known values as the fallback position and not the mean of the series. Secondly, in typical econometric analysis, test statistics would only be reported for the final estimation layout, some variables would have been dropped from the regression beforehand if certain probability thresholds are undercut. For our applications, we opted for a continuous rule as the choice of threshold values is arbitrary. The smaller the weighted R² the stronger the estimates are drawn towards our H0 – the value is equal to the recent three year average:

\begin{equation} X_{r,i,exante}^{j,"Support"}=wR_{r,i,j}^2 \left( a_{r,i,j}+b{r,i,j}t_{exante}^{c_{r,i,j}}\right)+\left(1-wR_{r,i,j}^2\right)X_{r,i,bas}^{j,"Data"} \end{equation}

where \begin{equation} wR_{r,i,j}^2=1-wSSE_{r,i,j}/wSST_{r,i,j} \end{equation}

and the weighted total sum of squares is defined analogous to equation below: \begin{equation} wSST_{r,i,j}=\sum_{expost}\left(X_{r,i,expost}^{j,"Data"}-X_{r,i,wAve}^{j,"Data"}\right)^2t_{expost} \end{equation}

with a trend weighted average \begin{equation} X_{r,i,wAve}^{j,"Data"}=\sum_{expost}X_{r,i,expost}^{j,"Data"}\cdot t_{expost}/\sum_{expost}t_{expost} \end{equation}

How is this rule motivated? If R² for a certain time series is 100%, in other words: for a perfect fit, the restricted trend estimate is fully drawn towards the unrestricted Step 1 estimate. If R² is zero, the trend curve does not explain any of the weighted variance of the series. Consequently, the support is equal to the ‘base data’. The ‘base data’ represent a three-year average around the last three known years. For all cases in between, the supports are the weighted average of the unrestricted trend estimate weighted with R² and the three-year average weighted with (1-R²). Generally, all trend estimates are restricted to the non-negative domain.

The above definition of supports works for series with expost data from CAPREG only as well as for those series with an extended set of observations (expostT, see above). The only difference is whether the three year average denoted above simply with “bas” is calculated using the three last years from set expost or from set expostT (BASM or BAST in ‘captrd\define_stats_and_supports.gms’).

Our objective function for Step 2 will be the sum of squared deviations from the supports defined above, weighted with the variance of the error terms from the first step: \begin{equation} Penalty=\sum_{r,i,j,expost}\left(\frac {X_{r,i,exante}^{j,"Trend"}-X_{r,i,exante}^{j,"Support"}}{\sqrt X_{r,i,verErr}^{j,"Step1"}}\right)^2 \end{equation}

where the weighted variance of errors is \begin{equation} X_{r,i,verErr}^{j,"Step1"}=wSSE_{r,i,j}/\left(\sum_{expost}t_{expost} -1\right) \end{equation}

The variance of the error term is used to normalise the squared deviations from all series which serves two purposes. First the weighted error variance is decreasing with the mean of the explanatory variable. Normalizing with it will hence ensure that the penalty targets relative rather than absolute deviations. Otherwise the solver would only tackle the deviations from “large” crops, say soft wheat, and more or less ignore the deviations of oats, for example. Secondly the deviations from the support are penalized stronger where the Step 1 trend had a high explanatory power and therefore a low variance of the error term.

The constraints in the trend projection enforce mutual compatibility between baseline forecasts for individual series in the light of relations between these series, either based on definitions as ‘production equals yield times area’ or on technical relations between series as the balance between energy deliveries from feed use and energy requirements from the animal herds. The set of constraints is deemed to be exhaustive in the sense as any further restriction would either not add information or require data beyond those available. The underlying data set takes into account all agricultural activities and products according to the definition of the Economic Accounts for Agriculture.

The constraints discussed in the following (from ‘captrd\equations.gms’) can be seen as a minimum set of consistency conditions necessary for a projection of agricultural variables. The full projection tool features further constraints especially relating to price feedbacks on supply and demand.

Constraints relating to market balances and yields

Closed market balances (CAPTRD eq. MBAL_) define the first set of constraints and state that the sum of imports (IMPT) and production (GROF) must be equal to the sum of feed (FEDM) and seed (SEDM) use, human consumption (HCOM), processing (INDM,PRCM,BIOF), losses (LOSM) and exports (EXPT):

\begin{align} \begin{split} X_{r,i,t}^{IMPT,Trend}+X_{r,i,t}^{GROF,Trend}&=X_{r,i,t}^{FEDM,Trend}+X_{r,i,t}^{SEDM,Trend}+X_{r,i,t}^{PRCM,Trend}\\ &+X_{r,i,t}^{INDM,Trend}+X_{r,i,t}^{BIOF,Trend}+X_{r,i,t}^{LOSM,Trend} \\ &+X_{r,i,t}^{HCOM,Trend}+X_{r,i,t}^{EXPT,Trend} \end{split} \end{align}

Where r are the Member States of the EU, i are the products, t the different forecasting years, corresponding to the equation. In the case of secondary products (dairy products, oils and oilcakes, for example) production is given on item MAPR. Domestic use DOMM (sum of the right hand side without exports) and net trade NTRD are defined in separate equations (DOMM_, NTRD_) not reproduced here. They do not act as constraints but permit a link to expert projections for EU markets in Step 3.

Secondly, production of agricultural raw products (GROF) is equal to yield times area/herd size (LEVL) where acts are all production activities (eq. GROF_):

\begin{equation} X_{r,i,t}^{GROF,Trend}= \sum_{acts}X_{r,i,t}^{acts,Trend}X_{r,LEVL,t}^{acts,Trend} \end{equation}

The market balance positions for certain products enter adding up equations for groups of products (cereals, oilseeds, industrial crops, vegetables, fresh fruits, fodder production, meat, eq. MBALGRP_). As an example, total cereal production is equal to the sum over the produced quantities of the individual cereals.

\begin{equation} X_{r,pro\_grp,t}^{MrkBal,Trend}= \sum_{i\in pro\_grp}X_{r,i,t}^{MrkBal,Trend} \end{equation}

Constraints relating to land use and cropping area

Adding up over the individual crop areas defines the total utilizable agricultural area (UAAR,LEVL, AREAB_):

\begin{equation} X_{r,LEVL,t}^{UAAR,Trend}= \sum_{crops}X_{r,LEVL,t}^{crops,Trend} \end{equation}

Adding up over the individual crop areas defines (in GRPLEVL_) the level of groups (set GrpC = {cereals, oilseeds, industrial crops, vegetables, fresh fruits, fodder production on arable land}):

\begin{equation} X_{r,LEVL,t}^{GrpC,Trend}= \sum_{crops \in GrpC}X_{r,LEVL,t}^{crops,Trend} \end{equation}

Adding up over mutually exclusive land use (in LANDUSEB_, for set LandUseARTO, see Annex: Tables 7-9) defines the total area (ARTO,LEVL):

\begin{equation} X_{r,LEVL,t}^{ARTO,Trend}= \sum_{LandUseARTO}X_{r,LEVL,t}^{LandUseARTO,Trend} \end{equation}

Constraints relating to agricultural production

Another Equation (OYANI_) links the different animal activities over young animal markets:

\begin{equation} X_{r,oyani,t}^{GROF,Trend}-X_{r,oyani,t}^{STCM,Trend}= \sum_{iyani\leftrightarrow oynai}X_{r,iyani,t}^{GROF,Trend} \end{equation}

Where oyani stands for the different young animals defined as outputs (young cows, young bulls, young heifers, male/female calves, piglets, lambs and chicken). These outputs are produced by raising processes, and apart from stock changes STCM (defined in Equation SOYANI_, not reproduced here), they are completely used as inputs in the other animal processes (fattening, raising or milk producing).

For those activites that have been split up in the database into a high and low yielding variant (DCOW, BULF, HEIF, GRAS) with 50% for each, this split is maintained (SPLITFIX_)

\begin{equation} X_{r,LEVL,t}^{splitactlo,Trend}= X_{r,LEVL,t}^{splitacthi,Trend} \end{equation}

The purpose of this split has been to permit an endogenous variation of yields also for animal activites, but so far no statistical information on the distribution of intensities has been available. Hence “intensive” has been defined to represent the upper 50% of the total distribution and it makes sense to maintain this split also in the baseline.

Animal herds (HERD) are related to animal activity levels through the process length in days (DAYS) via HERD_.

\begin{equation} X_{r,HERD,t}^{maact,Trend}= X_{r,LEVL,t}^{maact,Trend}\cdot X_{r,DAZS,t}^{maact,Trend} /365 \end{equation}

The process length is fixed to 365 days for female breeding animals (activities DCOL, DCOH, SCOW, SOWS, SHGM, HENS) such that the activity level is equal to the herd size3). For fattening activites the process length, net of any empty days (relevant for seasonal sheep fattening in Ireland, for example) times the daily growth should give the final weight after conversion into live weight with the carcass share carcassSh and consideration of any starting weight startWgt in FinalWgt_

\begin{align} \begin{split} X_{r,yield,t}^{maact,Trend}/carcassSh_{maact}=&startWgt_{maact}+X_{r,DAILY,t}^{maact,Trend}\\ &\cdot (X_{r,DAYS,t}^{maact,Trend}-X_{r,EDAYS,BAS}^{maact,data}) \end{split} \end{align}

As the daily growth is an important input into the livestock sector requirement functions it turned out useful to explicitely link it to the yields in terms of meat, both in the expost data (accounting identities in COCO) and here in the projections. Heavier animals require in this way a higher daily growth and/or a longer fattening period. For all inputs into the requirement functions hard constraints have been imposed (without the possibility to relax them in the solution process) to ensure that projected variables are fully in line with these contraints, mostly over bounds in ‘estimate_MS.gms’, but also through a specific (ad hoc) equation for male adult cattle that permits at most a daily growth of 0.4+500*0.0016 = 1.2 kg per day for a 500 kg final live weight, but more for heavier animals (DAILYUP_).

\begin{equation} X_{r,DAILY,t}^{bulf,Trend}\lt 0.4 + X_{r,meat,t}^{bulf,Trend}/carcassSh_{maact}\cdot 0.0016 \end{equation}

While all information for the requirement functions of CAPRI is projected consistently, they are not active in their detailed form in CAPTRD due to the complexity of the respective calculations. Instead these requirement functions are included in a simplified form as part of the balances for energy and protein requirements (REQS_) for each animal type maact:

\begin{equation} \sum_{feed}X_{r,feed,t}^{maact,Trend}X_{r,feed,t}^{Cont,Trend}= 0.998^t(a_{maact}^{Const}+a_{maact}^{Slope} X_{r,yield,t}^{maact,Trend}) \end{equation}

where Cont are the contents in terms of energy and crude protein. The left hand side of the equation defines total delivery of energy or protein from the current feeding practise per animal activity in region r, whereas the right hand side the need per animal derived from requirement functions depending on the main output (meat, milk, eggs, piglets born). The parameters a and b of the requirement functions are estimated from engineering functions as implemented in the CAPRI modelling system, and scaled so that the balance holds for the base year. The factor in front of the requirements introduces some input saving technical progress of -0.2% per annum.

The feeding coefficients multiplied with the herd sizes define total feed use for the different feeding stuffs ‘bulks’ (cereals, protein rich, energy rich, dairy based, other) and single nontradable feed items (grass, maize silage, fodder root crops, straw, milk for feeding, other fodder from arable land), technically in the same (GROF_) equation as equation below:

\begin{equation} X_{r,feed,t}^{GROF,Trend}=\sum_{maact}X_{r,feed,t}^{maact,Trend}X_{r,levl,t}^{maact,Trend} \end{equation}

Feed use of individual products must add up to the feed use of the ‘bulks’ mentioned above (in FEED_):

\begin{equation} X_{r,feed,t}^{FEDM,Trend}=\sum_{o\rightarrow feed}X_{r,o,t}^{FEDM,Trend} \end{equation}

Additional equations impose that certain stable relationships of agricultural technology are also maintained in projections:

  • Equation EFED_ ensures that feed use of non-tradable fodder items must be equal to production after accounting for losses.
  • Other equations (PosLo_, PosUp_) force the relation of seed use or losses to production (plus imports for losses) into a +-20% range around the base year value.
  • Production has to exceed seed use and losses (SEED_)
  • The ratio of straw to cereal yields is maintained at base year values (STRA_)
  • Livestock units per hectare are calculated (LU_) and may thus be subject to constraints (limiting their deviations from the supports, for example).

Finally there is an Equation (LABO_) ensuring that projections of family (LABH) and hired labour (LABN) in agriculture add up to total labour (LABO):

\begin{equation} X_{r,LABO,t}^{GROF,Trend}=X_{r,LABH,t}^{GROF,Trend}X_{r,LABN,t}^{GROF,Trend} \end{equation}

In the first place projections of family and hired labour follow from input coefficients combined with the activity levels, but the previous equation permits to apply bounds to the total.

Constraints relating to prices, production values and revenues

The check of external forecasts revealed that for some products, external price projections are not available. It was decided to include prices, value and revenues per activity in the constrained estimation process. The first Equation (EAAG_) defines the value (EAAG, position from the Economic Accounts for Agriculture) of each product and product group as the product of production (GROF) times the unit value prices (UVAG):

\begin{equation} X_{r,i,t}^{EAAG,Trend}=X_{r,i,t}^{GROF,Trend}X_{r,i,t}^{UVAG,Trend} \end{equation}

The revenues of the activities (TOOU, total output) for each activity and group of activities acts are defined in Equation REVE_ as:

\begin{equation} X_{r,TOOU,t}^{acts,Trend}=\sum_o X_{r,o,t}^{acts,Trend}X_{r,o,t}^{UVAG,Trend} \end{equation}

Consumer prices (UVAD) are equal to producer prices (UVAG) plus a margin (CSSP ) according to Equation UVAD_: 4) FIXME (fußnote61)

\begin{equation} X_{r,i,t}^{UVAD,Trend}=X_{r,i,t}^{UVAG,Trend}X_{r,i,t}^{CMRG,Trend} \end{equation}

Constraints relating to consumer behaviour

Human consumption (HCOM) is defined as per head consumption multiplied with population (HCOM_):

\begin{equation} X_{r,i,t}^{HCOM,Trend}=X_{r,i,t}^{INHA,Trend}X_{r,LEVL,t}^{INHA,Trend} \end{equation}

Consumer expenditures per caput (EXPE) are equal (via EXPE_) to human consumption per caput (INHA) times consumer prices (UVAD):

\begin{equation} X_{r,i,t}^{EXPE,Trend}=X_{r,i,t}^{INHA,Trend}X_{r,LEVL,t}^{UVAD,Trend} \end{equation}

Total per caput expenditure (EXPE.LEVL) must add up (in Equation EXPETOT_):

\begin{equation} X_{r,LEVL,t}^{EXPE,Trend}=\sum_i X_{r,i,t}^{ESPE,Trend} \end{equation}

Constraints relating to processed products

Marketable production (MAPR) of secondary products (sec) - cakes and oils from oilseeds, molasses and sugar, rice and starch - is linked in Equation MAPR_ to processing of primary products (PRCM) by processing yields (PRCY):

\begin{equation} X_{r,sec,t}^{MAPR,Trend}=\sum_{i \wedge sec \leftarrow i} X_{r,i,t}^{PRCM,Trend}X_{r,sec,t}^{PRCY,Trend} \end{equation}

In case of products from derived milk (mlkseco) – butter, skimmed milk powder, cheese, fresh milk products, cream, concentrated milk, whole milk powder whey powder, and casein – eq. MLKCNT_ requires that fat and protein content (MLKCNT) of the processed raw milk (MILK5)) be equal to the content of the derived products, after acknowlegding that small quantities of dairy products are themselves transformed to other dairy products (most relevant for processed cheese):

\begin{equation} X_{r,MILK,t}^{PRCM,Trend}X_{r,MILK,t}^{MLKCNT,Trend}=\sum_{mlk\, sec\, o} \left( X_{r,mlk\, sec\, o,t}^{MAPR,Trend} X_{r,mlk\, sec\, o,t}^{PRCM,Trend}\right) X_{r,mlk\, sec\, o,t}^{MLKCNT,Trend} \end{equation}

Marketable production of by-products from the brewery, milling and sugar industry (set RESIMP = { FENI, FPRI}) are derived from corresponding uses of related products (cereals and sugar, Equation MaprByFeed_):

\begin{align} \begin{split} X_{r,resimp,t}^{MAPR,Trend}= & \sum_{o \rightarrow resimp} \left(X_{r,o,t}^{HCOM,Trend} +X_{r,o,t}^{PRCM,Trend} +X_{r,o,t}^{INDM,Trend} +X_{r,o,t}^{BIOF,Trend}\right) \\ & \cdot \frac {X_{r,resimp,t}^{MAPR,bas}}{ \sum_{o \rightarrow resimp} \left( X_{r,o,t}^{HCOM,bas} +X_{r,o,t}^{PRCM,bas}+ X_{r,o,t}^{INDM,bas}+ X_{r,o,t}^{BIOF,bas}\right)} \end{split} \end{align}

Constraints relating to bio-fuel production

Marketable production (MAPR) of biofuels (seco_biof) derives (according to Equation BIOF_) from non agricultural production NAGR (e.g biodiesel from waste oil), from second generation production SECG , or through processing yields in terms of biofuels 6) (PRCB) from biofuel use of first generation feedstocks (BIOF):

\begin{equation} X_{r,seco\_biof,t}^{MAPR,Trend}=\sum_{stocks \rightarrow seco\_biof } X_{r,stocks,t}^{BIOF,Trend} X_{r,stocks,t}^{PRCB,Trend} \end{equation}

In case of ethanol there is another by-product, DDGS, which is usable as a feedstuff and produced according to by-product coefficients from cereals (DDGS_):

\begin{equation} X_{r,DDGS,t}^{MAPR,Trend}=\sum_{stocks \rightarrow DDGS} X_{r,stocks,t}^{BIOF,Trend} X_{r,stocks,t}^{PRCBY,Trend} \end{equation}

Constraints relating to policy

There are only a few constraints directly taken from an EU regulation: firstly, the acreage under compulsatory set-aside (abolished in the CAP Health Check of 2008) must be equal to the set-aside obligations of the individual crops (OSET_):

\begin{equation} X_{r,"levl",t}^{"OSET",Trend}=\sum_{cact} X_{r,"levl",t}^{cact,Trend} \frac {0.01 X_{r,"setr",t}^{cact,Trend}}{\left(1-0.01X_{r,"setr",t}^{cact,Trend}\right)} \end{equation}

Secondly, we have the quota products milk and sugar. The milk quotas on deliveries are acknowledged with a fixing on processing of cow milk without an explicit equation, taking into account that there are countries with persistent under- or over-deliveries. Given the expiry of milk quotas after 2015 this is largely irrelevant for current applications of CAPTRD. The sugar quotas, by contrast, are included as an upper bound (SugaQuot_) that may be relaxed (see Regulation 318/2006, Article 12) through industrial or biofuel use of sugar (and losses of sugar):

\begin{equation} X_{r,SUGA,t}^{MAPR,Trend} \le X_{r,SUGA,t}^{QUTS,Trend}+ X_{r,SUGA,t}^{INDM,Trend}+ X_{r,SUGA,t}^{BIOF,Trend}+ X_{r,SUGA,t}^{LOSM,Trend} \end{equation}

Finally, there are upper bounds on new plantings of vineyards according to the CMO for wine from Regulation 1493/1999

Constraints relating to growth rates

During estimation, a number of safeguards regarding the size of the implicit growth rates had been introduced in the course of various past CAPRI projects (bounds mainly found in ‘captrd\fix_est.gms’):

  • In general, input or output coefficients (yields) are not allowed to change by more than +/- 2.5 % per annum, with a higher ranges for feed input coefficients (+/- 10 % and +/ 5 % for non-marketable fodder).
  • The number of calves born per cow is may only change up to +/- 10 % around the base period value until the last projection year.
  • The number of young cows (or sows) needed for replacement may only change up to +/ 20 % around the base period value until the last projection year.
  • Final fattening weights must fall into a corridor of +/- 20% around the base period value.
  • Milk yields are assumed to increase at least by 0.25% and at most by 1.25% near the EU average with some correction for below or above average initial yields (in ‘captrd\comibounds.gms’).
  • Crop yields (except those of very hererogeneous crops like “other fruits” or “other fodder on arable land) should have a minimum yield growth of 0.5%.
  • Specific (and quite generous) upper limits are applied to prevent unrealistic crop yields (for example: 15 tons/ha for cereals)
  • Technical coefficients like contents of milk products or processing yields are also subject to plausible bounds.
  • Strong increases in pork and poultry production in the past are restricted by environmental legislation in force, notably the nitrate directive. Accordingly, yearly increases were restricted to +1% for pork in EU15 Member States (even more stringent for Denmark and The Netherlands) and to 1.5% for poultry. In the new MS these maximum growth rates are assumed to be half a percentage point larger, in line with a weaker implementation of environmental legislation. The same bounds are also applied to the corresponding activity levels.
  • A strong decrease of animal activity levels (below 20% of the base year) is not allowed.
  • Total agricultural area is not allowed to decline at a rate exceeding -0.2 % per annum.
  • Shares of arable crop on total arable area are bounded by a formula which allows small shares to expand or shrink more compared to crops with a high share. A crop with a base year share of 0.1% is allowed to expand to 2.5%, one of 10% only to 25%, and one of 50% to only 70%:

\begin{align} \begin{split} X_{r,"levl",t}^{arab,Trend} .up / lo = & X_{r,"levl",bas}^{arab,Trend} \\ & \pm 1/4 \left( \frac {X_{r,"levl",bas}^{arab,Trend}} {X_{r,"levl",bas}^{"arab",Trend}} \right)^{1/4} X_{r,"levl",bas}^{"arab",Trend} \; max\left(0.2,\frac {t-bas} {last-bas} \right) \end{split} \end{align}

  • However, in line with cross-compliance constraints from the CAP, permanent grass land must not decrease by more than 10% compared to the base year.
  • An upper bound of 1% applies to the yearly growth of the area of “other oils” (for unclear reasons)
  • Total labour must not deviate by more than 5% from forecasts based on coefficients estimated in an earlier study (“CAPRI-DYNASPAT”).
  • Changes in human consumption per caput for each of the products cannot exceed a growth rate of +/- 2% per annum. Due to some strong and rather implausible trends for total meat and total cereals consumption, the growth rate was restricted to +/- 0.8 % per annum for meat and +/- 0.4% per annum for cereals assuming that trend shifts between single items are more likely than strong trends in aggregate food groups.
  • A downward sloping corridor is defined for subsistence consumption of raw milk (in ‘captrd\comibounds.gms’).
  • Changes in prices are not allowed to exceed a growth rate of +/- 2% per annum, usually.
  • Expert supports for biofuel related variables are given high priority with mostly tight corridors around these supports (in ‘captrd\biobounds.gms’).
  • If a variable has dropped to zero according to recent COCO data it will be fixed to zero.

Step 2.2: Integration of specific expert support (Member State level or lower)

The definition of expert “supports” allows for provision of a mean and a standard deviation for all elements, and it is particularly useful for items for which the AgLink forcasts in step 3 are missing, or where there are other reasons for stability problems, such as missing historical data or very short time series

The expert supports are dealt with in ’captrd\expert_support.gms’. Currently, mainly three sources can be distinguished:

  • Support for the development of the sugar and sugar beet sectors, evolved from a small study with the seed production company KWS
  • Expert on the development of bio-fuel production (bio-ethanol, bio-diesel), and the input demand for the related feedstocks, mainly based on results from the PRIMES model
  • Expert supports for some key time series impacting on GHG emission for some Member States provided by the EC4MACS projects

The standard deviation is expressed by a “trust level” between 1 and 10.

The following table presents selected results related to the EU27 biomass feedstock for bioenergy production from the PRIMES7)) biomass component (also given for each MS):

Table 22: Selected results related to the EU27 biomass feedstock for bioenergy production from the PRIMES biomass component

Unit: ktoe (unless specified otherwise) 2000 2005 2010
Domestic Production of Biomass Feedstock 69,087 87,595 101,303
Crops 1,228 5,419 12,500
- Wheat 0 601 2,462
- Sugarbeet 0 1,291 4,518
- Sunflower/Rapeseed 1,228 3,527 5,520
- Lign. Crops 0 0 0
Agricultural Residues 4,194 6,428 7,200
Waste 19,990 26,002 28,054
Net imports of Biomass Feedstock 239 1,598 4,289
Pure Vegetable Oil as feedstock for bioenergy production 239 1,598 4,289
Cultivated Land (Kha) 896 3,022 5,422
Starch crops 0 320 1,218
Oil crops 896 2,654 4,031
Sugar Crops 0 48 172
Lignocellulosic crops 0 0 0

The above information on the biomass production is NOT used as the immediate input for CAPRI for several reasons. Converting from ktoe to 1000 tons (using 0.37 ktoe/1000t for cereals, 0.05 ktoe/1000t for sugar beet, 0.52 ktoe/1000t for rape seed) gives the production for the bio-fuel sector which matches with the market position “BIOF” = processing to biofuels. For cereals we have indeed 6.7 million tons from PRIMES in 2010 and 7.0 million tons according to CAPRI. For oilseeds we have to convert the PRIMES information in terms of oilseeds into a quantity of vegetable oil, giving approximately 5.5 mtoe / 0.52 ktoe/1000t * 0.4 [rape oil/ rape seed] = 4.2 million tons which is considerably larger than the results from CAPRI8) 1.8 million tons. A similar comparison for the sugar sector may point at conversion problems with the units. The PRIMES sugar beet production should correspond to a sugar quantity of 4.5 mtoe / 0.05 ktoe/1000t * 0.15 [sugar/sugar beet] = 13.5 million tons of sugar equivalents which is close to the total sugar production in CAPRI of 15.7 million tons. Apart from these unresolved differences in the ex post data the main reason for NOT using these biomass production quantities from PRIMES is conceptual: They are given from supply functions specific to the bio-fuel sector whereas CAPRI covers the whole production (mostly for food purposes) such that the use of exogenous information for parts of the total may create problems for the CAPRI market balances.

A similar consideration also applies to the area information from PRIMES which refers to the specific areas used for biofuel purposes, except for the area for lignocellulosic crops.

Basically, the information “close” to agriculture (feed stock use and required areas) has not been taken from PRIMES assuming that it is preferable to estimate those in the context of the agricultural sector model CAPRI. On the other hand, the information on the production of bioenergy, including its main technologies and pathways, was supposed to be given reliably from the PRIMES biomass component exactly because it covers beyond agriculture also forestry and various forms of waste. The next table focuses on those results that will be used as the immediate inputs for CAPRI (thus omitting bio-energy from forestry, for example).

First of all PRIMES offers net imports, production and demand quantities for the biofuels itself. Production of biodiesel is split up according to the technology in first generation and second generation technologies (FT diesel, HTU diesel, pyrolysis diesel). For ethanol such a breakdown is not given in terms of production volumes, but the PRIMES output includes among the installed capacities also those for fermentation of sugar crops, starchy crops and lignocellulosic crops, the latter identifying the share for second generation production of ethanol. The input for first generation production of biodiesel (through esterification) is “bioheavy” which includes pure vegetable oil from domestic production, but also from various forms of waste oil (recovered oils, biocrude, pyrolysis oil). In addition the market balance for bioheavy includes imports (pure vegetable oil, the larger part according to the previous table for biodiesel production, a smaller part for direct use as fuel) and demand quantities of bioheavy. These are the key inputs for CAPRI, plus the area of lignocellulosic crops that is also a direct input to CAPRI.

In addition, there is more information that may be used in the future. Biogas production is mainly based on sewage systems but in part it also relies on animal manure (whereas the German particularity of biogas from green maize is not yet included). Biogas production from manure might be coordinated between PRIMES and CAPRI in the future. Equally the PRIMES assumptions on the amount of crop residues usable for bio-energy are not yet cross-checked with CAPRI. Finally, it should be mentioned that the use of waste in the PRIMES tables refers to other sources of bioenergy (like municipal waste).

Table 23: Results on biofules of PRIMES model

Unit: ktoe (unless specified otherwise) 2000 2005 2010
Net imports of Bioenergy 400 1,731 5,820
Biodiesel 0 0 1,948
Bioethanol 0 20 1,130
Pure Vegetable Oil 8 390 505
Bioenergy Production 67,971 84,554 95,430
Biodiesel 610 2,548 6,578
- Biodiesel (1st gen.) 610 2,548 6,578
- FT diesel 0 0 0
- HTU diesel 0 0 0
- Pyrolysis diesel 0 0 0
Bioethanol 0 561 2,193
BioHeavy 1 83 605
- Recovered Oils 0 43 589
- Pure Vegetable Oil 1 40 15
- BioCrude 0 0 0
- Pyrolysis oil 0 0 0
BioGas 352 871 2,049
- Bio-gas 352 871 2,049
- Synthetic Natural Gas 0 0 0
Waste Solid 12,353 13,985 14,654
Waste Gas 1,898 3,537 4,538
Demand 68,372 86,285 101,250
Biodiesel 610 2,548 8,526
Bioethanol 0 581 3,234
BioKerosene 0 0 0
BioHydrogen 0 0 0
BioHeavy 9 473 1,110
BioGas 352 871 2,049
Waste Solid 12,353 13,985 14,654
Waste Gas 1,898 3,537 4,538
Capacities (Ktoe/yr) 10,440 16,067 26,754
Fermentation 134 1,127 4,104
- Sugar 0 551 2,103
- Starch 134 576 2,001
- Lignocellulosic 0 0 0
Esterification 1,141 4,170 9,021

In technical terms the PRIMES results are given as a set of Excel tables that is usually amended with each release in some detail. To extract these data a small GAMS program (‘merge.gms’) prepares strings that, when saved and reload with Excel, are interpreted as external links to the PRIMES files using the “Vlookup” function of Excel. The relevant data are written to a parameter p_PRIMESresults, including the following:

P_PRIMESresults(MS,BIOEshare,SECG,year)
= capacity, lignocellulosic / capacity fermentation

Otherwise the selection addresses directly certain lines of the PRIMES output.

In Step 3, results from external projections on market balance positions (production, consumption, net trade etc.) and on activity levels for EU aggregates (EU15, EU12) are added. Currently, these projections are provided by Aglink-COSIMO model projections. The baseline of Aglink-COSIMO integrates the market outlook results from DG-AGRI, but is also globally harmonised, so that it also enters the baseline generation for the market model of CAPRI.

Integration of results from another modelling system is a challenging exercise as neither data nor definitions of products and market balance positions are fully harmonized. That holds especially for Aglink-COSIMO, where at least in the past the mnemonics had even not been harmonized across equations of the model itself. After a restructuring exercise in 2010, that had somewhat been improved. The ingredients in the mapping process are first a list of the codes for the regions, products and items used in Aglink-COSIMO (‘baseline\aglink*_sets.gms’, where * can be 2009 or 2010 to differentiate the versions before and after the restructuring). A second program, (‘baseline\aglink*_mappings.gms’) links the CAPRI regions, products and items to the mnemonics and Aglink-COSIMO, and a larger program (‘baseline\loag_aglink*.gms’) then uses the mapping to assign them to the CAPRI code world.

Aglink-COSIMO currently features results at EU15 and EU12 level. It is hence not possible to funnel the Aglink-COSIMO results into Step 2 above without an assumption of the share of the individual Member States.

As DG-AGRI is often the main client of the CAPRI projections for the EU, it was deemed sensible to pull the projections towards the DG-AGRI baseline wherever the constraints of the estimation problem and potentially conflicting other expert sources allow for it. That is achieved by two assignments related to the objective function:

  1. Step 2 results (except those steered by other expert supports) are scaled proportionally to give MS level supports for step 3 that are consistent with the Aglink-COSIMO baseline (after adjusting for different definitions in the respective databases).
  2. The standard errors from the default trends are replaced with a special formula reflecting a high confidence in the Aglink-COSIMO derived supports.

More precisely, the weighted variance is replaced with the following setting for external supports (“XSupport” = AGLINK or expert supports):

\begin{equation} X_{r,i,"varErr"}^{j,"XSupport"}=\left(X_{r,i,"exante"}^{j,"XSupport"}\cdot 0.05/3 \cdot \left(10/X_{r,i,"trustlevl"}^{j,"XSupport"}\right)\right)^2 \end{equation}

The “trust level” in the last denominator is a scaling factor for the implied coefficient of variation. A higher trust level translates into a lower error variance of the external information. With a normal distribution we would have

  • at “trust level” = 10: X ∈ [-0.055*Mean, +0.055*Mean] with probability 99.9%
  • at “trust level” = 5: X ∈ [-0.275*Mean, +0.275*Mean] with probability 99.9%
  • at “trust level” = 1: X ∈ [-0.55*Mean, +0.55*Mean] with probability 99.9%

The default setting for “DGAgri” supports is a “trust level” of 5, which is a moderately high value to leave some distance for special cases that should be pulled very tightly towards their supports.

The Aglink-COSIMO projections currently run to 2020 or a few years beyond. For climate related applications CAPRI has to tackle projections up to 2030 or even 2050. CAPRI projections up to 2030 have been prepared in the context of EC4MACS project (http://www.ec4macs.eu). The methodology was quite simple: The year 2020 projection (usually prepared in the same run of CAPTRD) has been extrapolated in a nonlinear dampened (logistic) fashion (in ‘define_eu_supports.gms’) with some additional bounds to prevent unreasonable increases of certain variables (nonnegativity already provided a good lower bound). Together with the information in the time series database this has been an ad hoc but operational procedure to address the 2030 horizon, but it would have been inappropriate for a move to the long run up to 2050 as required for a recent study on behalf of DG CLIMA9).

For the long run evolution of food production a link has been established to long run projections from two major agencies (FAO 2006 and the IMPACT projections in Rosegrant et al 2009, see also Rosegrant et al 2008). This linkage required mappings to bridge differences in definitions (see ‘gams\global\f2050_impact.gms’ called when running ‘gams\global.gms’).

Furthermore, methodology was needed to avoid a break in the projections at the transition of medium run expert information (Aglink-COSIMO, up to 2020) and long run information (FAO/IFPRI for 2050). For this purpose a variable weighting scheme is introduced (in ‘gams\captrd\expert_support.gms’) that gives an increasing weight to our “long run” sources (FAO/IFPRI) as the projection horizon approaches 2050. This tends to give projections that gradually approach the long run sources, for example as in the case of pork production in Hungary (taken from a baseline established in November 2011).

Figure 11: Pork production in Hungary as an example for merging medium run and long run a priori information in the CAPRI baseline approach


Source: own elaboration

The example has been chosen because historical trends (and Aglink-COSIMO projections) on the one hand and long run expectations differ markedly. This is not unusual because medium run forecasts often give a stronger weight to recent production trends, often indicating a stagnating or declining production in the EU, whereas the long run studies tend to focus on the global growth of food demand in the coming decades. The simple trends (filled triangles) would evidently give unreasonable, even negative forecasts after 2030. Already the imposition of constraints from relationships to other series would stabilise the projections and imply some recovery after 2030 (filled squares). The year 2020 supports from Aglink-COSIMO (not shown) produces some upward correction of the step 2 results for 2020, giving a final projection (filled circles) of about 375 ktons for pork production in Hungary. This is also the starting point for the specification of the long run support (empty circles) which is a weighted average of two components. The first is a linear interpolation to the external projection from FAO/IFPRI for 2050 (empty triangles). The second is a nonlinear damped extrapolation of the medium run projection beyond 2020 (empty squares). Changing the weight for the first component (FAO/IFPRI support) with increasing projection horizon creates a long run target value (empty circles) that gives a smooth transition from the medium to the long run. As the final projections (filled circles) tend to follow these target values, they show a turning point in the future evolution of pork production in Hungary that ultimately reflects the consideration of increasing global demand underlying the FAO/IFPRI projections.

Evidently this approach is quite removed from economic modelling and it is not intended to be. Instead it tries to synthesize the existing projections from various agencies, each specialised in particular fields and time horizons, in a technically consistent and plausible manner. The specification of a constraint set and penalties of the objective function translates plausibility in an operational form. Technical consistency is imposed through the system of constraints active during the estimation.

Step 4: Breaking down results from Member State to regional and farm type level

Even if it would be preferable to add the regional dimension already during the estimation of the variables discussed above, the dimensionality of the problem renders such an approach infeasible. Instead, the step 3 projection results regarding activity levels and production quantities are taken as fixed and given, and are distributed to the regions minimizing deviation from regional supports. The aggregation conditions for this step (and correspondingly for the disaggregation of NUTS2 regions to farm types) are:

  • Adding up of regional production to Member State production (MSGROF_)
  • Adding up of regional agricultural and non-agricultural areas to Member State areas (eqs. MSLEVL_ and MSLANDUSE_)
  • Adding up of regional feed use by animal types to Member State values (MSFEEDI_).

The results at Member State level are thus broken down to regional level, ensuring adding up of production, areas and feed use:

\begin{equation} X_{MS,i,t}^{GROF,Trend}=\sum_{r\in MS}X_{r,i,t}^{GROF,Trend} \end{equation}

\begin{equation} X_{MS,"levl",t}^{j,Trend}=\sum_{r\in MS}X_{r,"levl",t}^{j,Trend} \end{equation}

\begin{equation} X_{MS,"levl",t}^{j,Trend}\cdot \left(X_{MS,"feed",t}^{j,Trend}+10 \right)=\sum_{r\in MS}X_{r,"levl",t}^{j,Trend}\cdot \left(X_{r,"feed",t}^{j,Trend}+10 \right) \end{equation}

The addition of the “10” (kg/animal) considerably improves the scaling in case of very small quantities (say 1 gram per animal). This is an example of a technical detail that may be crucial for numerical stability but usually cannot be reported fully in this documentation.

In addition to the above aggregation conditions, the lower level (NUTS2 or farm type) models only require the following constraints (as the market variables are already determined at the MS level):

  • Related to areas: area balance (Equation 57 FIXME), obligatory set aside (Equation 80 FIXME), aggregation to groups like cereals (0).
  • Related to yields: linkage of production, activity levels and yields (Equation 55 FIXME), stabilisation of straw yields (STRA_)
  • Related to animals: Nutrient balances (Equation 65 FIXME), local use of fodder (EFED_), definition of livestock density (LU_).

In order to keep developments at regional and national level comparable, relative changes in activity levels are not allowed to deviate very far from the national development. These bounds are widened in cases of infeasibilities.

Table below contains an example of the final output of the trends estimation task (C:\….CAPRI\STAR\star_2.4\output\results\baseline\results_BBYY.gdx), where BB stands for base year and YY for simulation year). Its main purpose is to provide with explanations on the variables of this output and, thus, a possibility to review the results in a step-by-step manner.

Table 24: Example of the final output of the trends estimation task and description of the variables

Product code Activity code Variables Years Explanations
19842009201020112012201320142015
SWHE SWHE BASM 8337Base year value from Build database workstep.
Penalty 0.2“squared root” difference between actual estimate and support value. The larger the value, the farer the estimate from support.
Lo 8080 Lower estimation bound.
DGAgri1 8876 8385 8046 8109 8632 8996 9167 Projection of Aglink-Cosimo for the EU15 aggregate scaled to fit the CAPRI database.10)
TrustLevl 3 Exogeneous value used for restricting min and max values of the support values. It is used in calculating lower and upper bounds (up and lo) of the projections.
data
BAST 8579 Simple average of the last 3 observation years available: 2012-2014.
B2000 7988
support 9167 Values estimated as linear combination of Step1 and BAST (BASM) with R2 as weight. They are replaced with expert support where applicable and then scaled. They are then stored as Support1. Support is then redefined based on the Aglink-Cosimo value.11)
support1 8943 (expert) support value, before introduction of Aglink-Cosimo calibration values.
step1 8918 1) Result of estimation of unconstrined trends
step2 88512) Results of solving the trend model with constraints at MS level and with support1
step3 89493) First, it is defined as results of solving trend model with constraints at MS level and with support (defined with Aglink-Cosimo value). Then, it is redifined with the results from solving this trend model with additional constraints at NUTS2 level.
wVarErr 259353
CoefVarErr 0.1
Extrap
Longrun 8553 8579 8633
Longrun1
P_Data 6975 9061 8614 8078 8139 8810 8789 Historical data – output of Build database. The last observation year – 2014.
series 69759061 8614 8078 81398810 8789 8949 Historical values (until 2014) and projected values (starting from 2015 with 5-year step, as defined in the GUI setting for the Trends projection task). The projected values are “copied” from Step 3.12)13)
up 8978 Upper estimation bound

Source: own compilation. Comments: SWHE in Product code column indicates soft wheat commodity. SWHE in Activity code indicates yield of soft wheat. The CAPRI model used for this example was calibrated to the projections of Aglink-Cosimo model.

Calibrating the global trade model

After the Task on Trends generation have been successfully completed, meaning that the projections for the defined (in GUI or a batch file) future years (currently, 2015, 2020, 2025 and 2030 are available) have been produced, the next step in the Baseline generation process (“Generate baseline” workstep in CAPRI GUI) is to calibrate the CAPRI global trade model. In the CAPRI GUI this refers to the task “Baseline calibration of market model”.

The calibration of the market model is steered by the C:\…\CAPRI\gams\capmod.gms file. The relevant parts of the code are activated by setting the setglobal 'BASELINE' to ON.

Stage I: Data preparation and balancing

The CAPRI database is composed of many different data sources, and requires data processing before the market model equations can be calibrated against the data set. Sources of potential problems include missing data and price-quantity framework that is inconsistent with the behavioural assumptions (e.g. profit maximizing producers, utility maximizing consumers).

Stage I of the market model calibration makes the CAPRI database consistent, and creates a dataset for the global agri-food markets against which the market model can be calibrated. As CAPRI is a comparative static model, the market model is calibrated only against the simulation year. But technically the CAPRI dataset is first made consistent to the model structure in the base year, and then shifted to the simulation year. More specifically the main steps in this stage include:

  1. Prepare the necessary data by
    1. loading them from various intermediate data files;
    2. mapping them to correct code lists;
    3. adjusting if necessary, often by applying security bounds;
  2. Ensure the consistency of the dataset to the market model structure for the base year (BAS)
  3. Shift the consistent dataset from the base year to the simulation year
  4. Ensure the consistency of the dataset to the market model structure for the simulation year (SIMY)

Data preparation

Before actually performing the calibration of the market model parameters, CAPRI first loads the necessary sets, parameters and data. These refer to periods (years), regions, activities, commodities, agricultural policies (e.g., premiums, quotas, rural development payments, set-aside requirements), environmental indicators, feed and fertilizer requirements, nutrient content of the commodities, global warming potentials, and other necessary input. The data loaded also includes two very important for this calibration step files: C:\…\CAPRI\output\results\capreg\res_BBCC.gdx and C:\…\CAPRI\output\results\baseline\trends_BBYY.gdx. The first file, res_BBCC.gdx, includes the results of generation of data for the base year (BB, currently 2012) for European countries and Turkey (CC) at NUTS0, NUTS1 and NUTS2 aggregation levels (GUI workstep “Build database”, task “Build regional database”). The second file, trends_BBYY.gdx, includes the results of trends generation task (see sections above) for all of the European countries and Turkey at NUTS0, NUTS1 and NUTS2 aggregation levels for the target simulation year (currently, 2030).

Constraints, requirements, policies and other data loaded including base year and trends data (i.e., of res_BBCC.gdx and trends_BBYY.gdx files) are subject to certain (mainly non-major) adjustments, additional calculations and assumptions that serve the purposes of data balancing, checking and provision of necessary for the calibration information. These include, for example, deleting positions not needed during the calibration run, (re-)assigning parameter names, deleting tiny quantities, checks for production without activity levels, possible empty projections and negative inland waters, setting the output coefficients for young animals equal to the ones at country (EU MSs, as young animals are not presented in the non-EU countries) level if missing at regional level, correcting fat and protein content of raw milk, assumption that second generation biofuels are produced 50/50 by agricultural residuals and new energy crops, etc.

Next, FAO data on the non-European countries as well as the trade flows among all of the countries (country trade blocks) accounted for in CAPRI are loaded. These FAO data together with the European data, which has already been subjected to certain adjustments as described in the previous paragraph, undergo the, so-called, data preparation step. This process is controlled by C:\…\CAPRI\gams\arm\market1.gms file which calls the C:\…\CAPRI\gams\arm\data_prep.gms file - specifically for this step. The data preparation step mostly refers to the base year and includes: among else, modification of GDP to fit the sum of final household expenditure, final government expenditure, gross capital formation and current account balance; import and export flows to be in line with net trade from production minus demand; scaling of demand side to fit production plus net trade; estimation of consumer prices for some countries, if missing; calculation of nutrient consumption per head and day as net of losses in distribution and households; scaling of outliers in prices etc. This step as well provides with estimation of yearly change factors beyond the base year: for prices, GDP, population, quantities and areas. Additionally, i) substitution elasticities (i.e., p_rhoX, where X indicates continuation of the parameter name) for bio-fuel feedstocks, feed, dairy products, sugar, table grapes, tobacco, cheese, fresh milk products, fruits, vegetables, distilled dried grains and rice for the CAPRI demand system14), and ii) transformation elasticity for oil seed processing and land supply elasticities are assigned.

Together with the data, equations of the CAPRI market module are loaded. They are described in detail in section Market module for agricultural outputs. These equations include behavioural functions for market demand including expenditure function, feed demand, blocks for dairy products, oilseeds processing and biofuels, netput functions, trade equations and balances, equations for prices and price transmission, functions for trade policies and for intervention stocks. There are additionally two crucial for data calibration functions: minimization of deviation of estimated values from the observed data. These two functions are described in detail later in this section.

Data balancing

After data preparation, data calibration for the base (currently, 2012) and simulation years (currently, 2030) take place. The main file steering the data balancing process is C:\…\CAPRI\gams\arm\data_cal.gms, which in turned is included in arm\market1.gms.

Data balancing for the base year

Data calibration for the base year aims at modifying the base year data to fit the system of equations of the market module. Some of the parameters defined in Stage I (e.g., p_rhoX) as well as parameter values and bounds defined at this stage are used. For example, starting points and corridors for quantity variables are set (e.g., calculating of world production to define correction corridor for calibration of production/demand/trade flows globally), global TRQ data are converted into ad valorem tariffs and checked for consistency and completeness, policy variables for the EU market model such as e.g., intervention stocks, are loaded. Also, starting values for prices of dairy products are estimated. In particular, a non-linear programming model is used, where the objective function is formulated as a Highest Posterior Density function. The value of this objective function equals sum of squared deviations of fat and protein prices, fat and protein content of milk products and processing margins of milk products from the respective means, weighted with the a priori variances. The means are defined as parameters based on the prices and fat and protein content of milk in the base year. The objective function is restricted by the balance: fat and protein of raw milk delivered to dairies shall equal fat and protein content of dairy products. The model is solved by minimizing the value of highest posterior density, hence minimizing the differences between the variables and their means. Prices of milk products are then defined as: product of fat and protein content and of far and protein prices plus processing margin. Furthermore, administrative prices for cereals and dairy products, and minimal import prices for cereals are constructed.

With the file C:\…\CAPRI\gams\arm\cal_models.gms, the so-called, models, used in calibration of data base are defined and solved. These models represent collection of equations, solutions of which provide with parameter values used for data calibration. The first model (MODEL m_trimSubsExports) calibrates the parameters of the function which defines the values of subsidized exports with and without the increase of market price above the administrative price. The second model (MODEL m_trimInterv) defines parameters of equations for intervention stock changes. It includes an objective function defined as a sum of: squared scaled difference of estimated and observed intervention stock changes and squared scaled parameters for behavioural function of intervention stock changes. This objective function is minimized subject to constraints represented by equations for intervention sales, probability for an undercut of administrative price, release from intervention stock, intervention stock changes and value of the intervention stock. The constraints are equations of the market model (see section Market module for agricultural outputs).

The model that calibrates base year data (MODEL m_calMarketBas) is defined in cal_models.gms file as well and includes almost all equations of the market model. In particular: equations for processing margin for dairy products (ProcMargM_), fat and protein balance between raw milk and dairy products (FatsProtBal_), processing margin for oilseeds ProcMargO_, processing yields of oilseeds (procYield_), 1st generation output of biofuels (prodBiof_) and total output of biofuels (MaprBiof_); balancing and adding up equations: equations which add production, processing demand, human consumption, feed demand quantities and quantities for processing from single countries (or block of countries) to trade blocks (ProdA_, ProcA_, HconA_, FeedUseA_, Proca_), adding up inside of the Armginton aggregate (total domestic consumption) (ArmBal1_), supply balance (SupBalM_) and imports and exports added up to bilateral trade flows (excluding diagonal element) (impQuant_); price equations: 1st stage Armington quantity aggregate (ArmFit1_), 2nd stage Armington quantity aggregate (ArmFit2_), import price relation to producer price (impPrice_), consumer price as average of domestic and import prices (arm1Price_), average price as average of different import prices (arm2Price_), average import price (arm2Val_), consumer price (Cpri_), producer price (PPri_), market price (PMrk_), average market price (MarketPriceAgg_); trade and tariff equations: aggregated trade flows (TradeFlowsAgg_), average transportation costs (TransportCostsAgg_), sum of imports under a non-allocated TRQ (TRQImports_), share of the tariff applied for the EU entry price system (EntryPriceDriver_), tariff specific entry price (tarSpecIfEntryPrice_), Cif price (cifPrice_), equation for defining levy (replaces tariff) in case of minimal border prices (FlexLevyNotCut_), cuting flexible levy by specific tariff if it exceeds the bound rate (FlexLevy_), tariffs under bi-lateral TRQs (trqSigmoidFunc_), specific tariffs as function of import quantities, if TRQ is present (tarSpec_, prefTriggerPrice_), tariffs under globally open (not bilaterally allocated) TRQs (tarSpecW_), ad valorem tariffs, if TRQ is present (tarAdval_), ad valorem tariff under not bilaterally allocated TRQs (tarAdValW_), export quantities from bi-lateral trade flows (expQuant_), exports included in the calculation of the export unit values excluding flows under double-zero agreements (nonDoubleZeroExports_), unit value exports (unitValueExports_, valSubsExports_), subsidised export values (EXPs_); equations for intervention stocks: probability weight for an undercut of administrative price (probMarketPriceUnderSafetyNet_), intervention sales (buyingToIntervStock_), intervention stock end size (intervStockLevel_), intervention stock changes (intervStockChange_), release from intervention stocks (releaseFromIntervStock_), aggregators for intervention purchases; equation for world market price (wldPrice_), and equation for minimization of deviation from given base year data and estimated data (NSSQ_). The model is solved by minimizing the SSQ value of NSSQ equation which is constrained by all of the rest of the equations included in the model.

The NSSQ equation is crucial to the data calibration as it, in its essence, minimizes the difference between the estimated and the observed (already adjusted at the previous stage) data of the base year. Its logic is analogues to the one of equation below:

FIXME im dokument nicht nummeriert \begin{equation} SSQ\cdot \sum_{RMS} \sum_{XXX} p\_weight_{RMS}^i=\sum_{RMS} \sum_{XXX} \left( \frac{v_{RMS,XXX}^i-DATA_{RSM,XXX,BAS}^i}{max(DATA_{RSM,XXX,BAS}^i,0.1) \cdot p\_weight_{RMS}^i} \right)^2 \end{equation}

where SSQ is an artificial variable to be minimized, indices RMS, XXX, BAS and i indicate, respectively, regions, commodities, base year and activities (e.g., production, processing, imports etc.), and p_weight is a parameter of weights between 1 and 100 assigned to regions and activities. These weights are necessary to achieve plausible calibrated values and their specification is the outcome of a trial and error process, inspecting results from data calibration and retrying. They depend on the results of global database and trends generation. On the right hand-side of the equation v stands for a variable to be estimated and DATA – for base year data already adjusted at the data preparation and balancing stage. Hence with this equation squared sum over regions and commodities of differences between estimated and observed values (and or quantities), these differences being scaled by the observed data times the weight parameters, is minimized. Respectively, calibrated base year data fits the system of the market equations, given certain parameter values, and resembles the observed data as closely as possible. The activities implied under the I index include quantities of production, human consumption, feed, processing, processed to biofuels, import and export, producer, consumer and market prices, difference between market prices and import prices to reduce differences between physical and Armington aggregation, consolidated gap between producer and market prices, processing margin, trade flows and transport costs.

The process of model solving is navigated with C:\…\CAPRI\gams\arm\data_fit.gms file. Its main function is to assure model solving by keeping the market balances closed and price system consistent. Because of the very large number of equations with the exact similar number of variables (36 thsds) that makes the system of equations square, as well as non-linear formulation of some of the equations, it is very likely that infeasibilities will occur during the model solving. To ensure the feasibility as far as possible, code elements such as widening of variable bounds, once they become binding, reducing non-smoothness of the functional forms and introduction of slack variables are introduced. More detailed information on this process can be found in a technical document by Wolfgang Britz and Heinz-Peter Witzke Infeasibilities in the market model of CAPRI – how they are dealt with at https://www.capri-model.org/docs/infes.pdf.

After solving the MODEL m_calMarketBas, the calibrated data are stored, new producer prices for agricultural outputs are set, sugar beet prices as a function of – sugar market price – sugar export price (pre-reform) or ethanol market price (post-reform) – processing yield (specific to CUR to calibrate to any set of projected beet prices) – levying model for A- and B- sugar (pre-reform) are calculated, share and shift parameters of CES-functions used in the Armington approach to determine import shares as a function of import prices are defined (file C:\…\CAPRI\gams\arm\cal_armington.gms). Furthermore, energy conversion factors for animal products are defined with MODEL m_fitFeedConv (in file C:\…\CAPRI\ gams\arm\feed_conv_decl.gms).

Data balancing for the simulation year
Aim of data calibration for the simulation year aims at generating such quantity, price and other market values (see list below) for the simulation year that they fit the system of equations of the market module and variable and parameter lower and upper bounds, as well as remain as close as possible to the values to which they are calibrated (e.g., trends, estimated with growth rates from the base year, Aglink-COSIMO values, GLOBIOM values etc.). Thus process, basically, follows similar approach as for the base year. There are, however, a few differences. The main is that the model used for calibration is MODEL m_calMarketFin. As the model for base year calibration (MODEL m_calMarketBas), it is defined in cal_models.gms file and includes similar equations of the market model with the exception of NSSQ_ equation. The latter equation is replaced by NSSQ1_. Its major difference from NSSQ_ is that DATA parameter includes not values of the base year, but values projected in trend generation step for some of the factors and values shifted to the simulation year based on assumptions or growth rates for the other factors. Thus, it is used for minimizing the differences between estimated and projected (with trend generation step or growth rates) values of the variables in question. Another difference of NSSQ1_ with NSSQ_ is that it includes the differences in intervention stock changes and excludes the differences in consumer prices and gaps between producer and market prices.

Before MODEL m_calMarketFin is solved, values of DATA parameter for the simulation year are defined. For example, administrative prices for dairy products and cereals and minimum import prices for cereals (in C:\…\CAPRI\gams\arm\prep_pol.gms) and policy data are defined, market prices, quantity variables are shifted with growth rates (C:\…\CAPRI\gams\arm\shift_quantities.gms) and tariffs are defined. Bounds for tariff variables, market prices, milk fat and protein as well as upper and lower limits on quantity variables are assigned as well. At this point, models to calibrate TRQs and entry price equations (MODEL m_fitTrq) and parameters of equations for the intervention stock changes (MODEL m_trimInterv) are solved as well (now for the simulation year, as before it was solved for base year values).

As m_calMarketBas model, m_calMarketFin model is solved by minimizing SSQ value by applying the approach of assuring feasibility via data_fit.gms file. After the solution is found and energy conversion factors for animal products are defined with MODEL m_fitFeedConv, the results are stored in C:\…\CAPRI\ output\results\baseline\data_market_1230.gdx.

Stage II: Elasticity trimming

Elasticity trimming in CAPRI aims at adjusting prior estimations of elasticities so that

  • the behavioural functions can be parameterized/calibrated to the given prices/quantity framework with the elasticities;
  • the calibrated elasticities satisfy regulatory conditions (homogeneity, additivity) and correct curvature in line with microeconomic theory;
  • the calibrated elasticities are as close as possible to prior elasticities (minimize deviation).

At first, parameters for land use market are calculated based on data from FAO world food market model. Among them are land use classes, crop yields, land demand of non-crop activities, areas used for fodder and average land price, total energy use for feeding and producer price of feed. Next, starting elasticity values, as well as their lower and upper bounds are loaded (e.g., demand elasticities used in SPEL/MFSS). Finally, elasticities are trimmed.

Elasticities trimming is controlled by C:\…\CAPRI\gams\arm\trim_par.gms file. The elasticity groups are: for calibration of demand and supply systems, feed demand system, oilseeds crush, oil processing and dairy industry. Elasticities of supply system, oilseeds crushing, oil processing and dairy industries, as well as for feed demand, are estimated with MODEL m_trimElas. It is solved by minimising absolute squares between given and calibrated elasticities including land elasticities (FitElas_) subject to the following constraints: marginal effects from price and quantity for current elasticity estimate (Hess_), homogeneity of degree zero for elasticities in prices (HomogN_), Cholesky decomposition of marginal effects to ensure correct curvature (Chol_), Ensure that own price elasticity exceeds yield elasticity * 1.5 (YieldElas_) and elasticities for total energy and protein intake from feeding (ReqsElas_).

Human consumption elasticities are estimated with MODEL m_trimDem by minimizing absolute squares between given and calibrated elasticities (FitElas_). Apart from the objective function the model includes several equations related to the definition of the demand system as Generalized Leontief, homogeniety of degree zero for elasticities in prices, additivity of income elasticities weighted with budget shares and elasticities for total calorie intake.

Stage III: Feed and fertilizer calibration

In this stage, the feed system is calibrated against the primary product prices of the market model (both marketable and non-marketable feed). The nutrient requirements of the crops are calculated together with the nutrient and energy requirement of the animal production activities.

The fertilizer flows are also calibrated here. The prior parameters for the fertilizer flows are defined based on the posterior mode of the base year, by modifying them with land use changes: the fertilization per ha is computed in the base year situation and then multiplied with the areas in the calibration point. The fertilizer flows are calibrated with the same calibration model as used for the base year in the database tasks.

The file C:\…\CAPRI\gams\capmod\def_fert_and_requirements.gms defines animal nutrient requirements and the nutrient requirements of the crops given trend forecasted yields. In particular, feed input coefficients are defined and calibrated, days in production process of fattening are defined, and manure output is taken into consideration as an input for fertilizer calibration. Fertilizer calibration is basically a merge of trend based forecasts from the ex-post CAPREG results. The fertilizer need is calculated as a function of yield, and adjusted according to the exogenous assumptions. Furthermore, crop nutrient need factors from trends are scaled and logistic function is used to calculate average growth rate of fertilizer use. The calculations must as well comply with the fertilizer equations of the supply model.

tage IV: Initialization and test run

After the behavioural blocks of the market model are calibrated (one-by-one), the whole model should be also tested for being correctly calibrated. In essence, the test initializes the model with the data against the model was calibrated, and then executes/solves the market model. In theory, a perfectly calibrated model can be solved in one single iteration, without adjustments in the values of the model variables. That is why the iteration limit is technically set to zero (i.e. not allowing for adjustment in the model variables) for the test solve. In practice, a number of infeasibilities might exist due to the accuracy of the numerical solution. But infeasibilities stemming from rounding errors must be small, so the sum of all infeasibilities gives a good indication on the quality of the model calibration.

At the final stage, some of the starting values and bounds for the market model are set, and agricultural policy data are loaded, adjusted and extended to the simulation year. The policy data include single area payment scheme, set-aside regulations, differentiation between old and new MSs payments, special national envelopes, Nordic schemes, changes in administrative prices, rural development policy and other major CAP post-2014 instruments. Policy files used for the baseline are located in C:\…\CAPRI\ gams\scen\base_scenarios folder. Their loading into the baseline process is controlled by CAP_2014_2020.gms file. With the data mentioned, the outcome of calibration of the CAPRI market module can be tested. In particular, the market model is solved at “trend values” and, thus, the calibration outcome is checked for fitting to the square system of market model equations. This is controlled by C:\…\CAPRI\.gams\arm\prep_market.gms file.

Technical remarks

Note that the task “Baseline calibration of market model” deletes the sim_ini.gdx file, but does not create a new one at the end of the calibration process. The new sim_ini.gdx file will be only created at the first simulation run after the calibration. That is also the reason why a specific GUI option 'Kill simini file' is provided for the simulation tasks. The simini file can be deleted upon request at the beginning of any scenario run, forcing CAPRI to re-create it before the scenario shock is introduced.

Technically, the calibration of the biofuel demand system and the Armington bilateral trade system is not directly linked to the BASELINE mode, but also executed every time when the simini file is missing (by create_sim_ini_gdx module).

Calibrating the supply models to the CAPTRD projection

Introduction

The supply side models of the CAPRI simulation tool are programming models with an objective function. If we want the optimal solution to coincide with the forecast procuced by the projection tools of CAPTRD, we need to ensure that first and second order optimality conditions (marginal revenues equal to marginal costs, all constraints feasible, and the solution is a maximum point) hold in the calibration point for each of the NUTS 2 or farm type models. The consequences regarding the calibration are threefold:

  1. Elements not projected so far but entering the constraints of the supply models (e.g. feed, fertilization) must be defined in such way that constraints are feasible,
  2. The cost function of the models must be shifted so that marginal costs and marginal revenues are equal in the calibration point.
  3. The curvature of the functions must be such that the solution obtained is a maximum, not a minimum or a saddle point.

Calibrating feed and fertilizer restrictions

The calibration of feed and fertilization restrictions happens in the file gams\capmod\def_fert_and_requirement.gms. As explained above, the requirement functions used in the projection tools are linear approximations for the ones used in the simulation tool; additional constraints restrict the feed mix in the supply modules.

It is hence necessary to find a feed mix in the projected point which exhausts the projected production of non-tradable feed and the projected feed mix of marketable bulk feeds (cereals, protein feed, …), fits in the requirement constraints and leads to plausible feed cost. In order to do so, the feed allocation framework used to construct the base year allocation of feedstuff to animals is re-used. The resulting factors are stored in external files and reloaded by counterfactual runs.

Similar to animal feed balance, the crop nutrient needs must be consistent with available projected nutrients from various sources. To find such a feasible point, the distribution of various fertilizer sources (manure, mineral fertilizers and crop residues) to crops estimated in the database (CAPREG), is shifted with changes in crop areas to make a first best guess (prior) of the allocation to crops in the baseline. This prior is used as the modal value of a probability density function of a Bayesian estimation, similar to the CAPREG procedure described in a previous section of the documentation. Thus, a crop nutrient allocation is sought that is in some sense “as similar” to the base year estimate as possible. The result of the fertilizer calibration for the baseline is stored in a GDX file for each country, found in the directory “results\fert”, from where it is loaded in simulations (by the file gams\capmod\load_fert_baseline.gms).

Calibrating the marginal cost functions

Since the very first CAPRI version, ideas based on Positive Mathematical Programming were used to achieve perfect calibration to observed behaviour – namely regional statistics on cropping pattern, herds and yield – and data base results as the input or feed distribution. The basic idea is to interpret the ‘observed’ situation as a profit maximising choice of the agent, assuming that all constraints and coefficients are correctly specified with the exemption of costs or revenues not included in the model. Any difference between the marginal revenues and the marginal costs found at the base year situation is then mapped into a non-linear cost function, so that marginal revenues and costs are equal for all activities. In order to find the difference between marginal costs and revenues in the model without the non-linear cost function, calibration bounds around the choice variables are introduced.

The reader is now reminded that marginal costs in a programming model without non-linear terms comprise the accounting cost found in the objective and opportunity costs linked to binding resources. The opportunity costs in turn are a function of the accounting costs found in the objective. It is therefore not astonishing that a model where marginal revenues are not equal to marginal revenues at observed activity levels will most probably not produce reliable estimates of opportunity costs. The CAPRI team responded to that problem by defining exogenously the opportunity costs of two major restrictions: for the land balance and for milk quotas. The remaining shadow prices mostly relate to the feed block, and are less critical as they have a clear connection to prices of marketable feed as cereals which are not subject to the problems discussed above.

The development, test and validation of econometric approaches to estimate supply responses at the regional level in the context of regional programming models form an important task for the CAPRI team. Up to now, there is still no fully satisfactory solution of the problem, but some of the approaches are discussed in here.

The two possible competitors are standard duality based approaches with a following calibration step or estimates based directly on the Kuhn-Tucker conditions of the programming models. Both may or may not require a priori information to overcome missing degrees of freedom or reduce second or higher moments of estimated parameters. The duality based system estimation approach has the advantage to be well established. Less data are required for the estimation, typically prices and premiums and production quantities. That may be seen as advantage to reduce the amount of more or less constructed information entering the estimation, as input coefficients. However, the calibration process is cumbersome, and the resulting elasticities in simulation experiments will differ from the results of the econometric analysis.

The second approach – estimating parameters using the Kuhn-Tucker-conditions of the model – leads clearly to consistency between the estimation and simulation framework. However, for a model with as many choice variables as CAPRI that straightforward approach may require modifications as well, e.g. by defining the opportunity costs from the feed requirements exogenously.

The dissertation work of Torbjoern Jansson (Jansson 2007) focussed on estimating the CAPRI supply side parameters. The results have been incorporated in the current version. The milk study (2007/08) contributed additional empirical evidence on marginal costs related to milk production, see also Kempen, M., Witzke. P., Pérez-Dominguez. I., Jansson, T. and Sckokai, P. (2011): Economic and environmental impacts of milk quota reform in Europe, Journal of Policy Modeling, 33(1), pp 29-52.

Calibration tests with supply models

After calibrating the various functions of the supply models, a test for successful calibration is carried out. The purpose of the test is to ensure that the models are really properly calibrated, and to avoid that a disequilibrium in the baseline is misinterpreted as the effect of some policy change in a scenario.

To test for successful calibration, all supply models are solved directly after the calibration, and the solutions are compared to the target values to which the models should have been calibrated. If the solutions deviate more than some tiny amount, an error message is produced and the execution terminated. The calibration test checks for deviations of activity levels and allocation of fertilizers to crops.

Sensitivity experiments with the supply models

The market model of CAPRI is solved with a simplified representation of the supply model behaviour (see model overview). Even in countries where we do have a detailed supply model representation of agriculture, the market model contains, for technical / numerical reasons, a simpler linearized supply model that is iteratively re-calibrated to reflect the results of the underlying supply models in the current iteration between supply and demand.

If the linearized supply models would replicate the behaviour of the supply models exactly, then no iterations would be needed. In fact, no programming models of supply would be needed either. However, the approximation is not perfect, and hence the model needs to iterate between supply and demand. Since these iterations with re-calibrations are time consuming, it is desirable to have as good an approximation as possible.

The functional form of the approximation is derived from a ”normalized quadratic profit function”, meaning that the supply of any commodity is a linear function of all prices divided by a price index. Hence, the slope of those supply functions is a square matrix equivalent to the Hessian matrix of the normalized quadratic profit function itself. In order to find out how the supply models, including all policies and constraints, respond to changes in market prices, the calibration procedures of the CAPRI system contains a suite of structured and automated simulation experiments. The GAMS scenario solver is used to vary prices one by one and evaluate changes in supply. The results are summarized in the matrix of second-order derivatives used in the supply approximation in the market model.

Baseline reproduction run

Not formally a component of the baseline calibration procedure, it has become an established habit to validate the calibration of supply using the simulation models themselves. There are many conceivable circumstances where the build-in calibration tests would pass, but a normal simulation nevertheless would not replicate the calibration point, for instance if some necessary and calibrated data is not properly loaded. Furthermore, the calibration does not produce the full report output, but only a limited set of variables. Therefore, a baseline reproduction is generally also needed in any applied project to establish the equilibrium comparison point.

In order to facilitate the evaluation of the calibration point, we run the same scenario as the one used to calibrate the model, but under a different name. “cal” and “ref” are frequently used name suffixes. Since the calibration is done country-wise, the result files of the calibration are found in one gdx-file per country. In order to be able to load all of them into the GUI and compare them to the outcome of the reproduction run, the utility “Merge country data” found under the work step “Tests” can be used. In the figure below the settings are shown that can read in all the country specific gdx files from the results directory (capmod), starting with the string “res_2_1230cap_after_2014_cal”, load a specified symbol (dataout), and store it back into a gdx file with the same name but without country suffix.

Figure 12: CAPRI settings: read in all the country specific gdx files from the results directory (capmod); load a specified symbol (dataout); store the data back into a gdx file with the same name but without country suffix
Source: own illustration

Then, the GUI can be used in a standard fashion to manually compare the activity levels reported after calibration with those computed in a baseline reproduction run.

1)
The only exceptions are the quota regimes on the milk and sugar markets which are recognised in the trend projections.
2)
For technical reasons some years are “obligatory” result years, for example the year immediately following after the last ex post year.
3)
The wording for animal numbers is a continuous source of confusion that may also affect older parts of this documentation or table headings from the CAPRI GUI. It is therefore recommendable to reserve the term “herd” strictly to stock variables (animals countable at a particular day) whereas the flow variable “produced heads per year” is the activity level for fattening activities.
4)
The symbol CSSP (initially for “consumer surplus”) is usually used for the welfare effects related to final consumers (currently expressed as equivalent variation). Consumer margins are stored on CMRG in the market model. This misuse of code CSSP in CAPTRD is due to historical reasons.
5)
This is somewhat indirectly related to processing of cow milk and sheep & goat milk over MAPR.MILK = PRCM.COMI + PRCM.SHGM with a processing yield PRCY.MILK = 1 and over the market balance for product MILK which ensures that, with minimal trade of raw MILK, most of MAPR.MILK will end up as PRCM.MILK.
6)
Note that the processing yields PRCY (say X tons of rape oil per ton of rape) are associated with the outputs, because there is just one possible input for the given output (say PRCY.RAPO = yield of rape in terms of rape oil). But in the case of bio-ethanol, for example, there are several feedstocks (wheat, barley etc) producing one output (ethanol). Hence the output coefficients PRCB are associated with the inputs (say PRCB.BARL = yield of barley in terms of ethanol) and we need different types of coefficients.
7)
PRIMES is a modelling tool for the EU energy system projections and impact assessment of the respective policies (see https://ec.europa.eu/clima/policies/strategies/analysis/models_en
8)
It appears that the CAPRI bio-fuel results of August 2011 are affected by reporting errors in the oilseeds and sugar sectors.
9)
Service contract on “Model based assessment of EU energy and climate change policies for post-2012 regime” (Tender DG ENV.C.5/SER/2009/0036), coordinated by the Energy-Economy-Environment Modelling Laboratory (E3MLab), National Technical University of Athens with the International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis (IIASA) and EuroCARE as subcontractors.
10)
Aglink-Cosimo model produces projections not for each EU MS, but for the EU aggregates: EU, EU “old” MSs and EU “new” MSs. During the calibration process these values are first scaled to better fit the CAPRI database. These scaled values are then used for the calibration procedure.
11)
The final version of the support value at MS level (if calibration to the projections of Aglink-Cosimo takes place), is calibration value derived from DgAgri1.
12)
Because the last observation year is 2014, values in 2015 are prjections.
13)
Values in 2020, 2025 and 2030 are projections as well but are not presented in this example.
14)
See section Overview on the market model on Overview of the market model “CAPRI comprises a two stage Armington system: on the top level, the composition of total demand from imports and domestic sales is determined, as a function of the relation between the domestic price and the average import price. The lower stage determines the import shares from different origins and defines the average import price.”
baseline_generation.1587797127.txt.gz · Last modified: 2022/11/07 10:23 (external edit)

Except where otherwise noted, content on this wiki is licensed under the following license: CC0 1.0 Universal
CC0 1.0 Universal Donate Powered by PHP Valid HTML5 Valid CSS Driven by DokuWiki